Wenar on why you shouldn’t try to help poor people

In all the discussion of Leif Wenar’s critique of Effective Altruism , I haven’t seen much mention of the central premise: that development aid is generally counterproductive (unless, perhaps, it’s delivered by wealthy surfers in their spare time). Wenar is quite clear that his argument applies just as much to official development aid and to the long-standing efforts of NGOs as to projects supported by EA. He quotes burned-out aid workers “hoping their projects were doing more good than harm.”

Wenar provides some examples of unintended consequences. For example, bednets provided to fight are sometimes diverted for use as fishing nets. And catching more fish might be bad because it could lead to overfishing (there is no actual evidence of this happening, AFAICT). This seems trivial in comparison to the lives saved by anti-malarial programs

It’s worth pointing out that, on Wenar’s telling, a project that gave poor people proper fishing nets (exactly the kind of thing that might appeal to the coastal villagers befriended by his surfer friend) might be even worse for overfishing than the occasional diversion of bednets.

Wenar applies his critique to international aid programs. But exactly the same kind of arguments could be, and are made, against similar programs at the national level or subnational level. It’s not hard to find burned-out social workers, teachers and for that matter, university professors, who will say, after some particularly dispiriting experience, that their efforts have been worse than useless. And the political right is always eager to point out the unintended consequences of helping people. But we have plenty of evidence, most notably from the last decade of austerity, to show that not helping people is much worse.

Reading Wenar, I was particularly struck by this casual dismissal of the lifesaving effects of programs like the WHO campaign against malaria and the PEPFARs aid initiative, which I initially found quoted with approval by Brian Leiter [1]
  

“The claim that there is “not much to show for [aid]” is simply false. Even among the “bottom billion”—the population of countries that have experienced the weakest economic growth over the last few decades—quality of life has increased dramatically. In 1950, life expectancy in sub-Saharan Africa was just 36.7 years. Now it’s 56 years, a gain of almost 50% … In reality, a tiny amount of aid has been spent, and there have been dramatic increases in the welfare of the world’s poorest people.” Now this is pure hooey. Even aid’s biggest boosters would cringe at the implication that aid had caused a 50 percent increase in sub-Saharan life expectancies. And what follows this astonishing statement is a tangle of qualifications and irrelevancies trailing off into the footnotes. To anyone who knows even a little about aid, it’s like MacAskill has tattooed “Not Serious” on his forehead.

I’m not an expert on classical logic [2] but I can count at least three fallacies here: guilt by assocation, an argument from incredulity and a false dichotomy. First, the fact the claim being attacked is supported by someone silly like McAskill says nothing about its truth value. Second, apart from anecdotes about disgruntled aid workers, Wenar offers nothing more in rebuttal than ‘I don’t believe it’.

Third, and most importantly, even if it’s not true that all of the increase in life expectancy is due to aid, that doesn’t prove that there was no contribution. Suppose that all the aid provided since the end of colonial rule (approaching one trillion $US) had only increased African life expectancy by one year, and had achieved nothing else. That’s still at least a billion years of extra life. To achieve that same gain with medical interventions in the rich countries of the world, it would be necessary to spend at least $US50 trillion (at the margin, interventions have typically already been adopted unless they cost more than $50-100 000 per life year gained)

Why, apart from the unpopularity of people like McAskill and SBF, has this shoddy stuff been taken seriously? Attacks on aid programs have a clear appeal on the ideological extremes of right and left, and a more diffuse appeal based on sloppy reasoning. The rightwing view is that aid (whether foreign aid or domestic social welfare programs) promotes dependency among recipients, when what is needed is trade and free markets. The far-left mirror image is that aid is designed to pacify the recipients who would otherwise mobilise as a revolutionary force. The sloppy middle view, typically associated with terms like ‘band-aid’, starts from the correct premise that, in a better world, aid would not be necessary, and goes on to to the non sequitur that giving aid is inconsistent with hopes for that better world.

Finally coming to the capitalized version of Effective Altruism, it’s true that it provides a way for predatory rich people to salve their consciences. But rich predatory people have always sought such salves. It’s better to use the guilt money to give effective help to poor people than to endow elite colleges and opera companies for other rich people (see, most recently, the Sacklers). If you don’t like this conclusion, the right response is to change the system that rewards destructive behavior with massive piles of wealth, while leaving billions of people in poverty. [3]. Until that effort succeeds, aid is the least bad option (and there is no reason not to do both).

[1] I’m aware that Leiter is something of a polarising figure. So bringing him in might be seen as an ad hominem on my part. If so, turnabout is fair play, I say.
[2] Modal logic is much more useful in the theoretical work I do.
[3] Ingrid’s work on limitarianism is having some impact here.

3 thoughts on “Wenar on why you shouldn’t try to help poor people

  1. Also, “many noble-sounding charities do not actually do much for the people they say they are helping” is GiveWell 101! I think that programs to give money directly to poor people and let them figure out how to spend it are usually on GiveWell’s short list of recommended charities.

    Doing nothing is a choice. Its generally a poor one. 

    The article in Wired seems to ignore the argument that if you give to people you know, they will tend to be people like you, and that $1000 buys much less good in the UK than in Bolivia. It does not even make clear whether Aaron the surfer is giving money to Indonesians, or just spending money in Indonesia (the money he spends to fly himself and his surfboard there sure does not go to poor villagers).

  2. I haven’t been following this, however, wouldn’t people in the affected areas be resistant, if harm were being done? 

    Perhaps we might just put some energy into making sure that people are listened to. That would be quicker than doing a bunch of studies and regressions. If the area weren’t a democracy, this could be a problem though. 

    Plus, why would this concept of harm not apply to helping rich people? I mean, first asking somebody if they want help is usually a good idea, regardless. And just because someone is poor, it doesn’t mean they can’t grasp the concept of overfishing. The issue is, is there something else they can eat in the meanwhile? (Or so I would think.)

    How come everyone is so quiet?

  3. The issue is not clear cut either way. I have been part of aid schemes that were largely wasteful and designed to foster the donor countries’ economic role rather than the recipient’s. Sometimes the most talented natives in the recipient country are diverted into unproductive roles with institutions such as the UN. Clearly other schemes with efforts designed to improve health are valuable. I knew very specific projects in areas, such as aquaculture, that yielded very high local returns.

    It is difficult. Rich countries will give more aid if they get an immediate return on that aid in terms of economic benefits. So gaining economic benefits is not an absolute criticism. But there is a tradeoff. Supporting a large computer installation that ties a developing country bureaucracy to a large foreign firm can be a problem.

    The plush offices and huge salaries of those employed by the UN largely, at times, on the basis of partisan political influences, have often been a disgrace. The key problem I think was that those employed were often incompetent rent seekers who travelled the world continuously but did very little work. The local employees were generally better people but they soon learn to play the elaborate UN games in order to retain their high salaries and to ensure their own survivability.

    Training and education policies in donor countries look good but those getting the training often become part of the brain drain to donor countries.

    Harry Clarke

Leave a comment